No 51
4th Quarter
2012
 
 
 
        T H E   F R E N C H   C E N T R E   F O R   R E S E A R C H   
        A N D   S T U D I E S   O N   T H E   W O R L D   E C O N O M  Y


The CEPII  - Past CEPII Newsletters - PDF Format  - Subscribe / Unsubscribe



C O N T E N T S:

FOCUS
Unconventional Monetary Policies

ON THE RESEARCH AGENDA
How House Prices Influence Unemployment: Cross-Country Evidence
The BRICs
Does Input-Iberalization Affect Firms' Choice of Technology ?
Have the ECB Unconventional Monetary Policies Lowered Market Borrowing Costs for Banks and Governments?
Unconventional Monetary Policies in the United States (2007-2010) in the Light of the Japanese Experience (1999-2006)

WORKING PAPERS -  RECENT PUBLICATIONS -  ON CEPII'S BLOG - FORTHCOMING




        F
        OCUS

Unconventional Monetary Policies


Monetary policy in exceptional times

The last five years have been a major challenge for the theory and practice of monetary policy. The Lehman Brothers collapse, on September 15, 2008, was followed by a dramatic increase in risk premia and a generalized panic on financial markets that spread from the United States to other parts of the world. As a result the assets fell substantially and the global economy was threatened by a credit crunch. The central banks reacted to the increase in risk premia by lowering their main interest rates. However, since the beginning of the subprime crisis the transmission of central bank rates to other interest rates, which is a key channel of conventional monetary policy, has been severely impaired. Moreover, the target policy rates in some countries have approached a level close to zero:  0-0.25% in the United States, 0-0.1% in Japan, 0.5% in the United Kingdom and 0.75% in the euro-zone.

Faced with these constraints, important central banks all systematically implemented unconventional monetary policies that can be categorized into three groups:
  • Expectation management strategy. Central bank commitment to keep policy rates at low levels can affect the expectations of the future interest rates and therefore reduce the long-term interest rates.
  • Changes in the composition of the central bank balance sheet by purchasing unconventional (risky) assets (credit easing).
  • Expansion of monetary base by providing banks with excess reserves at the central bank (quantitative easing).
While management is expected to communicate on monetary policy intentions, credit easing and quantitative easing require important changes in central bank balance-sheet management. In normal times, central bank assets in developed countries are typically composed of short-term safe assets and short-term loans to financial institutions. Since 2007 this traditional asset structure was modified by the following operations: i) exceptional longer-term liquidity provisions, ii) collateral rules easing and iii) risky asset purchases. Furthermore, the increase in central bank unconventional assets holdings resulted in overall balance sheet increase (quantitative easing).

Transformation of the role of the central bank

By implementing unconventional monetary policies the central banks endorsed new roles that were vividly criticized by some researchers and policy-makers and strongly encouraged by others. Central banks exceeded the conventional role of the lender of last resort function as they provided almost unlimited inexpensive funds to financial institutions and practically substituted themselves for the interbank market. They also enlarged eligible collateral and directly purchased unconventional risky assets. The Fed for instance exposed its balance sheet to important amounts of mortgage-backed securities and asset-backed securities, the ECB distributed unlimited three-year loans to banks and the Bank of Japan and the Bank of England purchased commercial papers and corporate bonds.

Furthermore, the purchases of longer-term government debt, conducted by four central banks mentioned above to different extent, diminished sovereign risk held by private agents. Additional consequence of longer-term government bonds purchases is that they helped governments to increase the borrowing without having to face higher interest rates. This is especially true in the United States, the United Kingdom and Japan where the long-term interest rates remain at a very low level (respectively around 1.7%, 1,7% and 0,8%) even though the governments increased substantially their debt. The central bank role in financing governments is a controversial one, and the monetary authorities never stated it as their objective.

Unconventional balance-sheet management and new central bank roles during the crisis may have important consequences on the behavior of market participants that are yet difficult to evaluate. The unlimited liquidity provision for instance can have perverse effects on the money market. Indeed, the important functions of interbank transactions such as information aggregation, price discovery and peer monitoring are reduced if unlimited liquidity is available from the central bank. In this case central bank interventions can create greater uncertainty in the interbank market rather than enhance liquidity exchange as intended. Moreover, such unlimited funding can contribute to maintain “alive” insolvent banks which would not start lending to the companies and households even with additional liquidity. This argument was often made with respect to the Bank of Japan (2001-2006), accused of artificially maintaining “zombie” banks and in this way postponing the recovery (Szczerbowicz, 2012b).

Another important issue is linked to the credit risk that the central banks accepted on their balance sheet. As the central banks' profits are transferred in fine to the Treasury, the taxpayers are directly impacted by the monetary policy decisions. The central banks protected themselves by imposing important cuts on accepted collateral and purchased assets. As long as the economy recovers as planned, they will make profit on these assets. If however another shock hits the economy and the existing problems are not solved, the central bank could bear losses and face the dilemma whether to ask the government for rescue (recapitalization, lending of sovereign bonds) or just monetize the loss.

Finally, the critics mention the inflation threat as a consequence of unconventional measures. However, the impact of unconventional monetary policies on inflation is more complex. First, from an empirical and a theoretical point of view it is not certain  that such an effect would appear. Second, if inflation is a potential danger, it can also have a beneficiary effect in a deflationary environment.

Effectiveness of unconventional measures

There is a rapidly growing literature that empirically evaluates the effectiveness of unconventional monetary policies. Unconventional asset purchases, and long-term government bonds in particular, were found to be effective in lowering long-term interest rates in the United States (Hamilton and Wu, 2011; Szczerbowicz, 2011) and in the United Kingdom (Joyce, 2010). Szczerbowicz (2012a) evaluated the impact of all ECB unconventional monetary policies on the euro-area sovereign spreads and found that the sovereign bond purchasing programs proved to be the most effective in reducing these spreads. The strong impact in the euro-area periphery suggests that the central bank intervention in sovereign market is particularly effective when the sovereign risk is important.

The effects of exceptional liquidity provisions are more controversial. On the one hand, they relieved liquidity-constrained banks and prevented the credit crunch. This was particularly the case of the ECB three-year loans granted to banks (3y LTRO). The banks borrowed more than €1 trillion which covered their immediate funding needs and prevented them from selling assets and cutting some types of lending (Aglietta et al. 2012). On the other hand, their impact on the interbank lending is uncertain and contested by several studies (Taylors and Williams, 2009, Angelini et al., 2011).

The empirical results provide some positive evidence on the effectiveness of unconventional monetary policies on market interest rates and in particular on longer-term interest rates. However, the ultimate objective of unconventional policies was an increase in lending to companies and households and these unconventional measures were not accompanied by a rise in higher monetary aggregates. The pass-through of lower interest rates induced by unconventional policies to lending rates to companies and households would be a key element to evaluate overall effectiveness of these measures.

References:
Aglietta, M., Carton, B. & Szczerbowicz, U. , La BCE au chevet de la liquidité bancaire, La Lettre du CEPII N°321, May 2012.
Angelini, P., Nobili, A. &  Picillo, C., The interbank market after august 2007: What has changed, and why? , Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 43(5), 923–958, 2011.
Hamilton, J. D. & Wu, J. C., The effectiveness of alternative monetary policy tools in a zero lower bound environment, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 44, 3–46, 2011.
Joyce M. A. S., Lasaosa, A., Stevens, I. & and Tong, M. The Financial Market Impact of Quantitative Easing in the United Kingdom, International Journal of Central Banking, vol. 7(3), pages 113-161, September 2011.
Szczerbowicz, U., Are Unconventional Monetary Policies Effective?, Working Papers CELEG 1107, Dipartimento di Economia e Finanza, LUISS Guido Carli, 2011.
Szczerbowicz U., Unconventional monetary policies in the United States (2007-2010) in the light of the Japanese experience (1999-2006), CEPII Working Paper, Forthcoming 2012a.
Szczerbowicz, U., Have the ECB unconventional monetary policies lowered market borrowing costs for banks and governments?, CEPII Working Paper, Forthcoming 2012b.
Taylor, J. B. and Williams J. C. , A black swan in the money market American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 1(1), 58, 2009a
.


Top of page



How House Prices Influence Unemployment: Cross-Country Evidence


   

Many commentators have noted a close link between house price busts and jobless recoveries. The negative relationship between house prices and unemployment can however accommodate very different interpretations: house prices move positively and unemployment negatively with the business cycle, so whatever drives the cycle could explain their comovement. Moreover, house prices can decrease when unemployment goes up because of reduced consumption on all goods, and on housing services in particular. However, in this paper we investigate the opposite causal effect: the effects of house price movements on unemployment.

As in the paper on current accounts “House prices drive current accounts: evidence from property tax changes”, property taxes are used as an instrument for house pricing. First results point out that house prices have a causal effect on unemployment, notably through the channel of investment. We find that a decrease of 10% in house prices yields to a 2% increase in the unemployment rate, which has an very large effect  on the economy (it would for example account for almost the entirety of the recent increase in unemployment in the United States). Our data is a country-year dataset spanning 34 countries and the period 1970-2010. The use of country-level data for this type of study is essential as house prices do not vary much at the country-level (except in the US, this variation is for instance used in Chaney and al. (2012)).

Part of the story behind this causation is one of allocative effects. Interestingly, rising (declining) house prices do not only lead to hiring (firing) construction workers, it also leads to more employment fluctuation in more collateral-sensitive industries. We follow here the methodology developed by Rajan and Zingales (1998). We also investigated the effects of falling aggregate demand triggered by declines in house prices leading to consumer debt overhang.

Finally, the increase in unemployment caused by house price busts requires more public revenues at a time when private capital flows out of the country. This can explain a strong correlation between private and public flows, which has been a feature of the last European crisis (in Spain and in Greece), and may call for more public scrutiny of the evolution of house prices in the management of sudden stops.

François Geerolf & Thomas Grjebine

Chaney, T., Sraer, D. &Thesmar, D., (2012), The Collateral Channel: How Real Estate Shocks affect Corporate Investment, American Economic Review.
Rajan, R. Zingal�s, L., (1998), Financial dependence and Growth, American Economic Review.

The BRICs

   This book helps understand the major problems the BRICs (Brazil, Russia, India, China) are facing. On the domestic side, they have to increase the income and improve the living conditions of their population, and to reduce the fault lines that divide their societies. On the other side, they have to take part in the overhaul of the global economy toward sustainable growth, based on innovation and less resource-intensive modes of production and consumption. What are the effects of their emergence on the organization of industrial production in the world? What are the implications of their growth on the global energy balance and on the environment?

The book presents the history of the BRICs and their emergence at the beginning of the XXIth century. For China and India, this is a come-back to the forefront of the world after a long eclipse (Chapter I). Already, since the early- or mid- XXth century, these countries had undertaken painful efforts to modernize their economy. Capitalizing on the attainments and drawing lessons from past failures in the 1990s, they launched the great transformation of their economies (Chapter II). Thanks to their new economic strategy, they have built on their strengths and seized the opportunities offered by the globalization process. Demography has undoubtedly been a major asset, as in Brazil, India and China, the working age population boomed and, in the four countries, labor productivity increased. (Chapter III). Based on their comparative advantages in manufacturing, in services or/and in natural resources, they have carved out a leading position in international trade and their supply and demand has now a crucial influence on most global markets (Chapter IV). This successful integration into international trade would not have been possible without their openness to foreign investment (Chapter V). The four BRICs have so far confirmed the predictions concerning their potential growth but they will face many obstacles on the long way towards catching up the advanced economies (Chapter VI). They have become major players in the global economy (in trade, finance, investment, innovation, migrations), but they have still to clarify the role they intend to play in global governance (Chapter VII).

Andrea Goldstein & Fran�oise Lemoine



Does Input-Liberalization Affect Firms' Choice of Technology ?

   Foreign technology transfers play a key role in the economic growth of developing countries. In this research the effects of input-trade liberalization on firms' decision to upgrade technology embodied in imported capital goods are investigated. A theoretical model of endogenous technology adoption and heterogeneous firms is developped. Assuming that imported intermediate goods and high-technology are complementary and the existence of technology adoption fixed costs, the model predicts a positive effect of input tariff reductions on firms' choice of technology to source capital goods from abroad. This effect is heterogeneous across firms depending on their initial productivity level. Using firm-level data from India, we demonstrate that the probability of importing capital goods is higher for firms producing in industries that have experienced greater cuts on tariff on intermediate goods. Our findings also suggest that only those firms in the middle range of the productivity distribution have benefited from input liberalization. These empirical results are robust to alternative specifications that control for other reforms, industry, firm characteristics, alternative measures of technology.




Have the ECB Unconventional Monetary Policies Lowered Market Borrowing Costs for Banks and Governments?

    This paper evaluates the impact of all ECB unconventional monetary policies implemented between 2007 and 2012 on bank and government borrowing costs via event-based regressions. The borrowing conditions for banks are represented by money market spreads and covered bond spreads while the sovereign bond spreads reflect government borrowing costs. The results show that only the most spectacular ECB unconventional monetary policies, namely sovereign bond purchases (SMP and OMT), covered bond purchases (CBPP 1 and 2) and 3-year refinancing operations (3y LTRO) diminished significantly borrowing costs for banks and government.

Money market spreads were most relieved after the 3-year loans were distributed to banks (3y LTRO) and after the ECB started buying longer-term bank debt (CBPP 1 and 2) but remained unaffected by smaller liquidity measures which suggests that credit risk was the banks' principal concern. The covered bond markets reacted the most to the long-term sovereign bond purchasing program (SMP) but also to the short-term sovereign bond purchasing program (OMT), covered bond purchases (CBPP 1 and 2) and the 3-year LTRO. Covered bonds, as a source of banks long-term refinancing, were in line with expectations reactive to measures addressed to banks (CBPP, 3y LTRO). However, the strong reaction to sovereign bond purchases (SMP and OMT) suggests that this measure had an impact on broader class of long-term assets as it diminished the risk of sovereign default.

Finally, both OMT and SMP had an important impact on the cost of government borrowing in countries directly threatened by loosing access to financial markets: the effects range from 35 basis points (Italy) to 476 basis points (Greece). As a comparison, we show that the U.S. and U.K. sovereign spreads also fell following the sovereign bond purchases announced by the Fed and the Bank of England but the magnitude of the effect was much smaller: respectively 5 and 9 basis points. The strong impact in the euro area suggests that the central bank intervention in sovereign market is particularly effective when the sovereign risk is important.



Unconventional monetary policies in the United States (2007-2010) in the light of the Japanese experience (1999-2006)

   

This paper compares unconventional monetary policies implemented in the United States (2007-2010) with the first big-scale unconventional experience in Japan (1999-2006). Both central banks implemented three types of unconventional monetary policy: expectation management, monetary base expansion and purchases of risky assets. We argue however that the U.S. unconventional balance-sheet management was “asset-driven” whereas the Japanese more “liabilities-driven”. While the BOJ intended to increase the excess reserves to banks so that they expand their lending, the Fed intervened directly in financial markets they wanted to support. Different balance sheets management reflect different underlying economic problems in the U.S. and Japan (bad security vs bad loan issue) and different expected results (lowering specific asset prices vs fighting deflation). Accordingly, the Fed's exit strategy is more challenging that the BOJ's exit and requires additional tools. We investigate the impact of non-standard measures on the private banks' balance sheets, and in particular on lending to other banks, companies and households. The interbank lending slowed down in both countries but in the U.S. to much bigger extent. On the contrary, the lending to companies diminished more in Japan as there was double deleveraging process in firms and financial institutions.

Furthermore, the empirical evidence for the effectiveness of unconventional monetary policies in Japan and in the U.S is discussed. It appears that in Japan “expectation management strategy” contributed to lowering long-term yield, whereas in the U.S. the sovereign bond purchases proved more effective. The different effect of non-orthodox tools in Japan and in the U.S. can be attributed to overall strategies of the central banks: the Fed purchased aggressively risky assets while the BOJ intended to provide large amounts of excess reserves to banks without taking too much risk.

Finally, risks connected to unconventional policies are analyzed. While inflation does not seem to be the immediate danger, the important credit risk on the Fed's balance sheet brings up concerns about overstepping into fiscal policy and threatens the Fed's independence. On the other hand, the reluctance of the BOJ to employ credit and quantitative easing more aggressively undermined its effectiveness in countering deleveraging pressures and deflation.





WORKING PAPERS


G-MonD Policy Paper - Ending the Euro Area Crisis: Crossing the River by Feeling the Stones
N°2012-39  November 2012
   We review the solutions put forward between May 2010 and September 2012 by European policymakers to address the four aspects of the euro-area crisis: (i) the sovereign debt crisis, (ii) the banking crisis, (iii) the competitiveness crisis and (iv) the governance crisis. We show that progress has been uneven in each of these areas. We highlight the key issues that need to be addressed for a comprehensive solution to be found. These include more realistic, coordinated deleveraging, more ambitious structural reforms, prioritization of macroeconomic surveillance, the revamping of fiscal policymaking, effective bank supervision and restructuring, the recognition that the risk of “fiscal dominance” cannot be completely eliminated, and the introduction of a European-level social initiative.

Résumé en français
Agnès Bénassy-Quéré, Yves-Emmanuel Bara, Benjamin Carton, Christophe Destais, Sophie Piton



Does Migration Foster Exports? An African Perspective
N°2012-38  December 2012
   This paper assesses the impact of migration on export performances. In particular, it highlights and helps understand how African migrants foster African trade. Relying on a new dataset on international bilateral migration recently released by the World Bank spanning from 1980 to 2010, we estimate a gravity model that deals satisfactorily with heteroscedasticity, zero bilateral flows and endogeneity. Our results indicate that the African Diaspora has a positive effect on African exports, suggesting a substitution effect between migrants and institutions, with the existence of migrant networks compensating for weaker contract enforcement, for instance. This positive association seems to be particularly important for the exports of differentiated products. Focusing on intra-African trade, we find that the pro-trade effect of African migrants is more important when migrants are established in a non-neighboring country, and in African countries whose ethnic groups are different from their own.
Hélène Ehrhart, Maëlan Le Goff, Emmanuel Rocher, Raju Jan Singh



The Impact of Market Regulations on Intra European Real Exchange Rates
N°2012-37  December 2012
   We study the contribution of market regulations in the dynamics of the real exchange rate within the European Union. Based on a model proposed by De Gregorio et al. (1994a), we show that both product market regulations in nontradable sectors and employment protection tend to inflate the real exchange rate. We then carry out an econometric estimation for European countries over 1985-2006 to quantify the contributions of the pure Balassa-Samuelson effect and those of market regulations in real exchange-rate variations. Based on this evidence and on a counter-factual experiment, we conclude that the relative evolution of product market regulations and employment protection across countries play a very significant role in real exchange-rate variations within the European Union and especially within the Euro area, through theirs impacts on the relative price of nontradable goods.
Agnès Bénassy-Quéré, Dramane Coulibaly



The ECB Unconventional Monetary Policies: Have They Lowered Market Borrowing Costs for Banks and Governments?
N°2012-36  December 2012
   This paper evaluates the impact of all ECB unconventional monetary policies implemented between 2007 and 2012 on bank and government borrowing costs. We employ event-based regressions to measure the effect of each policy. The borrowing conditions for banks are represented by money market spreads and covered bond spreads while the sovereign bond spreads reflect government borrowing costs. The results show that sovereign bond purchasing programs (SMP, OMT) proved to be the most effective in lowering longer-term borrowing costs for both banks and governments with the largest impact in periphery euroarea countries. The strong impact in the euro-area periphery suggests that the central bank intervention in sovereign market is particularly effective when the sovereign risk is important. Furthermore, both covered bond purchase programs and 3-year loans to banks reduced bank refinancing costs.



Exchange Rate Volatility, Financial Constraints and Trade: Empirical Evidence from Chinese Firms
N°2012-35  December 2012
   This paper studies how firm-level export performance is affected by RER volatility and investigates whether this effect depends on existing financial constraints. Our empirical analysis relies on export data for more than 100,000 Chinese exporters over the period 2000-2006. We confirm a trade-deterring effect of RER volatility. We find that firms tend to export less and fewer products to destinations with higher exchange rate volatility and that this effect is magnified for financially vulnerable firms. As expected, financial development does seem to dampen this negative impact, especially on the intensive margin of export.



Multinational Retailers and Home Country Exports
N°2012-34  December 2012
   This paper questions whether the overseas expansion of a country’s retailers fosters overall bilateral exports towards these host markets. To address this question, we consider an empirical trade model, where the foreign sales of multinational retailers reduce the fixed and variable trade costs of their conational firms towards the same destination markets. We test our model with data on bilateral exports on a large panel of countries and the foreign sales of world’s largest one hundred retail companies over the 2001-2010 decade. We find a strong positive effect of the overseas presence of retailers of a given country on its exports to those markets. This outcome is far from being trivial, as most products sold in retailers foreign outlets are locally-produced. It testifies that the overseas presence of a country’s retail companies contributes to the reduction of trade costs towards these markets for other firms of the origin country. Our result is robust to different specifications, the use of different sets of instrumental variables and econometric approaches.
Angela Cheptea, Charlotte Emlinger, Karine Latouche



Food Prices and Inflation Targeting in Emerging Economies
N°2012-33  November 2012
   The two episodes of food price surges in 2007 and 2011 have raised the question of how monetary authorities should react to such external relative price shocks. These inflation shocks have been particularly challenging for developing and emerging economies’ central banks who have adopted inflation targeting strategies during the last decade. We develop a new-Keynesian small open-economy model that distinguishes three price indexes: an overall consumer prices index, the exact index of core inflation based on sticky prices, and a proxy for the core inflation index based on non-food prices. We show that nonfood inflation is a good proxy for core inflation in high-income countries, but not for middle-income and low-income countries. Although, in these countries we find that associating non-food inflation and core inflation may be promoting badly-designed policies, and consequently central banks should target headline inflation rather than non-food inflation. This result holds because non-tradable food goods represent a significant share in total consumption. Indeed, the poorer the country, the higher the share of purely domestic food goods in consumption and the more detrimental lack of attention to the evolution in food prices.
Marc Pourroy, Benjamin Carton, Dramane Coulibaly



Fiscal Consolidations and Banking Stability
N°2012-32  November 2012
   We empirically investigate the effects of fiscal policy on bank balance sheets, focusing on episodes of fiscal consolidation. To this aim, we employ a very rich data set of individual banks’ balance sheets, combined with a newly compiled data set on fiscal consolidations. We find that standard capital adequacy ratios such as the Tier-1 ratio tend to improve following episodes of fiscal consolidation. Our results suggest that this improvement results from a portfolio re-balancing from private to public debt securities which reduces the risk-weighted value of assets. In fact, if fiscal adjustment efforts are perceived as structural policy changes that improve the sustainability of public finances and, therefore, reduces credit risk, the banks’ demand for government securities increases relative to other assets.
Jacopo Cimadomo, Sebastian Hauptmeier, Tom Zimmermann



The Contribution of the Yen Appreciation since 2007 to the Japanese Economic Debacle
N°2012-31  November 2012
   The Japanese yen in 2012 remains 25 percent above its value in 2007. Exports, industrial production, and stock prices crashed after 2007 and have yet to regain their pre-crash values. This paper investigates the contribution of the yen appreciation to this economic disaster. Evidence from Johansen maximum likelihood and dynamic ordinary least squares (DOLS) estimation indicates that a 25 percent appreciation reduces long run exports by 8 – 18 percent. Panel DOLS evidence reveals that the appreciation especially depressed exports in the automobile sector. Regression evidence implies that the yen appreciation caused yen export prices to fall 29 percent in the automobile sector and 22 percent in the electrical and electronics sector. Finally, evidence from estimating exchange rate exposures indicates that the yen appreciation has reduced profitability significantly in the automobile and electronics sectors. Japanese firms could mitigate some of these harmful effects by focusing on innovating rather than competing based on price in commoditized industries.
Willem Thorbecke



Are the Benefits of Export Support Durable? Evidence from Tunisia
N°2012-30  November 2012
   This paper evaluates the effects of the FAMEX export promotion program in Tunisia on the performance of beneficiary firms. While much of the literature assesses only the short term impact of such programs, we consider also the longer term impact. Propensity-score matching difference-in-difference and weighted least squares estimates suggest that beneficiaries initially see faster export growth and greater diversification across destination markets and products. However, three years after the intervention, neither the growth rates nor the export levels of beneficiaries are significantly different from those of non-beneficiary firms. Exports of beneficiaries remain more diversified, but the diversification does not translate into lower volatility of exports. There is also no evidence that the program produced spillover benefits for non-beneficiary firms. Taken together, these results suggest that export promotion programs may in some cases induce firms to diversify without creating other durable benefits.
Olivier Cadot, Ana M. Fernandes, Julien Gourdon, Aaditya Mattoo



Les dessous de la dette publique japonaise
N°2012-29  octobre 2012
   



Invoicing Currency, Firm Size, and Hedging
N°2012-28  October 2012
   We use the results of a survey conducted on a sample of 3,013 exporting firms located in 5 EMU countries to explore the link between the invoicing currency of exports, firm size, and hedging. About 90% of firms in the sample invoice exports in their (producer) currency. Large firms are more likely to use another currency. The aggregate use of the euro is thus 15 percentage points lower when firms are weighted by their size than for the average firm. This heterogeneity is robust to controlling for determinants of the invoicing choice stressed by the literature. We however show that large firms and firms pricing in another currency as the euro are also more likely to hedge against exchange rate risk. An IV estimation shows the causal impact of access to hedging on the choice of the invoicing currency. We find (large) firms having access to hedging being more likely to invoice in the importer’s currency.
Julien Martin, Isabelle Méjean



Product relatedness and firm exports in China
N°2012-27  October 2012
   We propose the first evaluation using micro-level data of the expected growth gains from the consistency of activities with local comparative advantage. Using firm level data from Chinese customs over 2000-2006, we investigate the relationship between the export performance of firms and how their products relate to local comparative advantage. Our key indicator measures the density of the links between a product and the local product space. It hence combines information on the intrinsic relatedness of a good to that on the local pattern of specialization. Our results indicate that exports grow faster for goods that have denser links with those currently produced in the firm’s locality. The density of links between products thus seems to yield export-enhancing spillovers. We however also show that this positive effect of product relatedness on export performance is mainly limited to ordinary trade activities and domestic firms. It is also stronger for more productive firms, suggesting that spillover diffusion may be hindered by insufficient absorptive capacity.
Sandra Poncet, Felipe Starosta de Waldemar



Export upgrading and growth: the prerequisite of domestic embeddedness
N°2012-26  October 2012
   Our work contributes to the literature relating output structure and economic development by showing that growth gains from upgrading are not unconditional. Relying on data from a panel of Chinese cities, we show that the level of capabilities available for domestic firms operating in ordinary trade is an important driver of economic growth. However, no direct gains emanate from the complexity of goods produced by either processing-trade activities or foreign firms. This suggests that the sources of product upgrading matter, and that domestic embeddedness is the key for capacity building and technology adoption to be growth enhancing.
Sandra Poncet, Felipe Starosta de Waldemar



Time to ship during financial crises
N°2012-25  October 2012
   We show that the negative impact of financial crises on trade is magnified for destinations with longer time-to-ship. A simple model where exporters react to an increase in the probability of default of importers by increasing their export price and decreasing their export volumes to destinations in crisis is consistent with this empirical finding. For longer shipping time, those effects are indeed magnified as the probability of default increases as time passes. Some exporters also decide to stop exporting to the crisis destination, the more so the longer time-to-ship. Using aggregate data from 1950 to 2009, we find that this magnification effect is robust to alternative specifications, samples and inclusion of additional controls, including distance. The firm level predictions are also broadly consistent with French exporter data from 1995 to 2005.
Nicolas Berman, José de Sousa, Philippe Martin, Thierry Mayer



Foreign ownership wage premium: Does financial health matter?
N°2012-24  October 2012
   Microeconometric studies have shown that foreign-owned firms pay a wage premium in developing countries. This paper investigates one of the possible channels that explain why foreign firms pay higher wages than their domestic counterparts in developing economies. Under imperfect financial markets, foreign affiliates have a greater access to funds to finance high-technology investments and to compensate their workers. The empirical analysis relies on firm-level data from Romania during the 1998-2006 period. The identification strategy exploits the financial sector reform in Romania during this period as a proxy of an exogenous shock of improvement of financial resources. Changes in the IMF financial reform index across manufacturing industries are related to the ownership status of the firm to investigate how the differential access to finance of foreign firms shapes wages. The findings suggest that a one-standarddeviation increase in the financial reform index increases firms’ wages by 7 percent for domestic firms and 11.2 percent for foreign affiliates. These results are mainly driven by foreign firms from developed countries that might benefit from connections with foreign-owned banks. These findings are stable and robust to different sensitivity tests related to the financial reform indicator, other reforms and industry trends.



Tax Reform and Coordination in a Currency Union
N°2012-23  October 2012
   We propose a two-country DSGE model to analyze short-term and long-term impact of a modification of consumption and labor tax rate in one country in a currency union. The model embodies the fact that firms differ in their pricing behavior after a VAT tax increase. Due to the common monetary policy, national tax policies have large spill-overs on the rest of the currency union. Furthermore, a fiscal devaluation is different from a nominal devaluation due to the common monetary policy.



The Unequal Effects of Financial Development on Firms' Growth in India
N°2012-22  October 2012
   This paper investigates the microeconomic effects of financial development on economic growth. The increased availability of credit is usually expected to improve firms’ growth due to the elimination of credit constraints. We investigate this question using a survey of Indian firms in the manufacturing industry during the period 1997-2006, in a context of rapid economic growth and underlying structural changes. We examine how changes in the level credit over GDP in Indian States affected firms’ value added and capital used for production. The baseline estimations show that financial development has boosted within-firm growth in India. Our findings also suggest that the impact of financial development on firms’ growth is heterogeneous across firms and industries. Credit expansion has a greater effect on firms that are initially larger, more productive or profitable. The effect of financial development is less heterogenous in sectors relying on external finance, where both medium-size and large firms have expanded more rapidly than small firms. These results are robust to various specifications that allow to control for other reforms taking place simultaneously, or for potential reverse causality.



Pegging emerging currencies in the face of dollar swings
N°2012-21  October 2012
   The aim of this paper is to study ruptures of exchange-rate pegs by focusing on the fluctuations of the anchor currency. We test for the hypothesis that currencies linked to the USD are more likely to loosen their peg when the USD is appreciating, while sticking to it otherwise. To this end, we estimate smooth-transition regression models for a sample of 28 emerging currencies over the 1994-2011 period. Our findings show that while the real effective exchange rates of most of these countries tend to co-move with that of the USD in times of depreciation, this relationship is frequently reversed when the US currency appreciates over a certain threshold. Such nonlinear effects are especially at stake in Asia where growth is export-oriented.
Virginie Coudert, Cécile Couharde, Valérie Mignon



On the links between stock and commodity markets' volatility
N°2012-20  October 2012
   This paper investigates the links between price returns for 25 commodities and stocks over the period from January 2001 to November 2011, by paying a particular attention to energy raw materials. Relying on the dynamic conditional correlation (DCC) GARCH methodology, we show that the correlations between commodity and stock markets evolve through time and are highly volatile, particularly since the 2007-2008 financial crisis. The latter has played a key role, emphasizing the links between commodity and stock markets, and underlining the financialization of commodity markets. At the idiosyncratic level, a speculation phenomenon is highlighted for oil, coffee and cocoa, while the safe-haven role of gold is evidenced.
Anna Creti, Marc Joëts, Valérie Mignon



European Export Performance
N°2012-19  October 2012
   Competitiveness has come to the forefront of the policy debate within the European Union, focusing on price competitiveness and intra-EU imbalances. But how to measure competitiveness properly, beyond price or cost competitiveness, remains an open methodological issue; and how can we explain the resilience of producers located in the EU to the competition of emerging economies? We analyze the redistribution of world market shares at the level of the product variety, as countries no longer specialize in sectors or even products, but in varieties of the same product, sold at di fferent prices. We decompose changes in market shares into structural e ffects (geographical and sectoral) and a pure performance e ffect. Our method is based on an econometric shift-share decomposition and we regard the EU-27 as an integrated economy, excluding intra-EU trade. Revisiting the competitiveness issue in such a perspective sheds new light on the ongoing debate. From 1995 to 2009 the EU-27 withstood the competition from emerging countries better than the US and Japan. The EU market shares in the upper price range of the market proved quite resilient, by combining good performance and favorable structure e ffects, unlike the US and Japan. Finally, while most developed countries lose market shares in high-technology products to developing countries, the EU is slightly gaining, bene fiting of a favorable structure e ffect.
Angela Cheptea, Lionel Fontagné, Soledad Zignago



The Few Leading the Many: Foreign Affiliates and Business Cycle Comovement
N°2012-18  August 2012
   This paper uses micro-data on balance sheets, trade, and the nationality of ownership of firms in France to investigate the effect of foreign multinationals on business cycle comovement. We first show that foreign affiliates, which represent a tiny fraction of all firms, are responsible for a high share of employment, value added, and trade both at the national and at the regional levels. We also show that the distribution of foreign affiliates across regions differs with the nationality of the parent. We then show that foreign affiliates increase the comovement of activities between their region of location and their country of ownership. We find that intra-firm trade in intermediate inputs is a significant channel of influence of business cycle comovement. These findings suggest that a non-negligible part of business cycle comovement is driven by a few multinational companies, and that the international transmission of shocks is partly due to linkages between affiliates and their foreign parents.
Jörn Kleinert, Julien Martin, Farid Toubal



Native language, spoken language, translation and trade
N°2012-17  July 2012
   We construct new series for common native language and common spoken language for 195 countries, which we use together with series for common official language and linguistic proximity in order to draw inferences about (1) the aggregate impact of all linguistic factors on bilateral trade, (2) whether the linguistic influences come from ethnicity and trust or ease of communication, and (3) in so far they come from ease of communication, to what extent translation and interpreters play a role. The results show that the impact of linguistic factors, all together, is at least twice as great as the usual dummy variable for common language, resting on official language, would say. In addition, ease of communication is far more important than ethnicity and trust. Further, so far as ease of communication is at work, translation and interpreters are extremely important. Finally, ethnicity and trust come into play largely because of immigrants and their influence is otherwise difficult to detect.



Assessing the price-raising effect of non-tariff measures in Africa
N°2012-16  August 2012
   In spite of widespread tariff reductions, intra-African borders remain thick. Regional trade is inhibited by inadequate transportation infrastructure, but also by various government-imposed measures. This paper combines price data from the World Bank’s International Comparison Project (ICP) with the new TRAINS database on non-tariff measures (NTMs) to estimate their effect on consumer prices for selected consumption products. Results based on panel regressions on 1260 country-product pairs suggest that, after controlling for tariffs, systematic cross-country cost-of-living differences, and product-specific unobservables, SPS measures contribute to raise the price of African foodstuffs by 14%. At the product level, rice and other cereals, some types of meat (e.g. poultry), and edible oils tend to fetch high AVEs. Combining our estimates with data on household expenditure patterns from Kenya’s household survey, we show that the effect is regressive, raising the cost of living by 9% for poor households.
Olivier Cadot, Julien Gourdon



International Migration and Trade Agreements: the new role of PTAs
N°2012-15  July 2012
   This paper investigates empirically the role of Preferential Trade Agreements (PTAs) as determinants of migration inflows for 29 OECD countries in the period 1998-2008. By increasing information about signatory countries, PTAs are expected to drive migration flows towards member countries. Building on the empirical literature on the determinants of migration, I estimate a modified gravity model on migration flows providing evidence of a strong positive effect of PTAs on bilateral migration flows. I also consider the content of PTAs as a further determinant of migration, finding that visa-and-asylum and labour market related provisions, when included in PTAs, stimulate bilateral migration flows. Finally, by comparing the average effects of PTAs on migration flows and on trade, I show that PTAs stimulate bilateral migration flows more than trade in final goods. PTAs might be used by government to increase inflows of immigrant workers in the case of labour shortages or population ageing.




CEPII Working Papers are available free, on-line, in PDF format.

Top of page

        RECENT PUBLICATIONS


Issue 134 - Q2   2013
Issue 133 - Q1   2013
    Introduction: Recent international macroeconomic and financial issues
    Jean-Pierre Allegret, Cécile Couharde, Valérie Mignon
Issue 132 - Q4   2012
Issue 131 - Q3   2012
Issue 130 - Q2   2012


New year, new challenges , January 12, 2024, Antoine Bouët

The 2023 CEPII's Programme of work: focus on shocks and deep transformations of global economy , February 22, 2023, Antoine Bouët, Christophe Destais, Lionel Fontagné

, June 15, 2022, Cecilia Bellora, Kevin Lefebvre, Malte Thie

Trade datasets are not the right starting point to discuss trade in natural gas , April 4, 2022, Cecilia Bellora, Pierre Cotterlaz, Malte Thie

Europe after Covid 19: How €750 billion could reboot the EU , July 6, 2020, Anne-Laure Delatte

Recent drug shortages in Europe overshadow half a century of trade surpluses , June 2, 2020, Pierre Cotterlaz, Guillaume Gaulier, Aude Sztulman

Covid-19 Crisis: Tracking uncertainty in the US economy , April 21, 2020, Aymeric Ortmans, Fabien Tripier

Vietnam: The last dragon - 2/2: Resilience faced with international tensions , February 17, 2020, Michel Fouquin, Jean-Raphaël Chaponnière

Vietnam: the last dragon - 1/2: International Openness: A Guide to Vietnam's Economic Policy , February 14, 2020, Michel Fouquin, Jean-Raphaël Chaponnière

CEPII Country Profiles upgrade , November 20, 2019, Équipe Profils du CEPII / CEPII Profiles team

Europe in the Sino-American Trade War , September 30, 2019, Cecilia Bellora

, December 3, 2019, Fabien Tripier

France takes on Silicon Valley: Washington threatens tariffs over GAFA tax , July 16, 2019, Anne-Laure Delatte

EU competition policy should not be sacrificed but trade policy should be strengthened , July 2, 2019, Sébastien Jean, Anne Perrot, Thomas Philippon

Trade wars and global value chains: Shooting oneself in the foot , April 23, 2019, Cecilia Bellora, Lionel Fontagné

Addressing macroeconomic imbalances within the euro area: still a long road ahead , April 15, 2019, Virginie Coudert, Cécile Couharde, Carl Grekou

The "new silk roads": an evaluation essay
(4/4): Obstacles on the road
, May 13, 2019, Michel Fouquin, Jean-Raphaël Chaponnière


The "new silk roads": an evaluation essay
(3/4): China as a global player in globalization
, April 29, 2019, Michel Fouquin, Jean-Raphaël Chaponnière


The "new silk roads": an evaluation essay
(2/4): The Belt, Corridors and roads
, April 1, 2019, Michel Fouquin, Jean-Raphaël Chaponnière


The "new silk roads": an evaluation essay
(1/4): A Chinese vision of globalization
, March 18, 2019, Michel Fouquin, Jean-Raphaël Chaponnière


Sovereign risk and asset market dynamics in the euro area , January 14, 2019, Erica Perego

Deep PTAs, Global Value Chains and Migration , December 2, 2018, Gianluca Orefice

Why the WTO needs reform , November 16, 2018, Sébastien Jean

, October 29, 2018, Anne-Laure Delatte

Let their people come: Migrants as drivers of knowledge diffusion , October 8, 2018, Dany Bahar, Hillel Rapoport

, October 5, 2018, Joachim Jarreau, Cristina Mitaritonna, Sami Bensassi

Banks Defy Gravity in Tax Havens , September 21, 2018, Vincent Bouvatier, Gunther Capelle-Blancard, Anne-Laure Delatte

France and Europe in Globalization , April 12, 2018, CEPII

US withdrawal from the Paris Agreement: can States lead the fight to reduce carbon emissions? , February 2, 2018, Cecilia Bellora, Jean Fouré

Left behind by protectionism: learning from the Bush administration's steel tariffs , January 31, 2018, Sébastien Jean, Ariell Reshef

Japan-Europe, the unnoticed megadeal , October 26, 2017, Sébastien Jean

Latin America : Investing in infrastructure is key to achieve long term sustained growth , June 27, 2017, Camilo Umana Dajud

The international elasticity puzzle is worse than you think , May 11, 2017, Lionel Fontagné, Gianluca Orefice, Philippe Martin

Firms outcomes and local migrant workers supply , March 7, 2017, Cristina Mitaritonna, Gianluca Orefice, Giovanni Peri

Multi-destination exporters coping with stringent technical regulations , February 20, 2017, Lionel Fontagné, Gianluca Orefice

Donald Trump fighting a losing battle against geography , February 3, 2017, Lionel Fontagné, Gianluca Santoni

The effects of Trumpian uncertainty on U.S. economy , January 25, 2017, Fabien Tripier, Stéphane Lhuissier

Carrier International: the beginning of the unraveling of globalization? , December 15, 2016, Jean-Francois Boittin

Why denser areas are more productive , December 2, 2016, Lionel Fontagné, Gianluca Santoni

Improving the G20 process , October 24, 2016, Christophe Destais

Comments on IMF’s “Global Trade: What’s behind the Slowdown?” – or why there is more to trade slowdown than weak demand , October 18, 2016, Sébastien Jean

Brazil: restoring fiscal austerity while preserving public services , September 7, 2016, Cristina Terra

Should we fear the Brexit uncertainty?
IMF versus Krugman
, August 19, 2016, Stéphane Lhuissier, Fabien Tripier


In search of a liquid asset for European financial markets , July 15, 2016, Francesco Molteni

How Multi-Destination Firms Shape the Effect of Exchange Rate Volatility on Trade , June 14, 2016, Jérôme Héricourt, Clément Nedoncelle

Through the lenses of the natural rate of interest, European monetary policy appears to be too loose since 2015 , May 27, 2016, Stéphane Lhuissier

Towards an international financial public order , February 9, 2016, Christophe Destais

Falling oil price and appreciating dollar: is it normal? , January 27, 2016, Virginie Coudert, Valérie Mignon

Best wishes for 2016! , January 1, 2016, Sébastien Jean

Enforcement of FTAs: lessons for TPP and new trade agreements , December 15, 2015, Sébastien Jean, Kevin Lefebvre

Georges Sokoloff , December 12, 2015, Michel Fouquin, Sébastien Jean, Jean-Pierre Saltiel

Business Cycles in Europe since 1970 , December 10, 2015, Stéphane Lhuissier

Trillions in Transition: Growing our Way out of Climate Change? , December 7, 2015, D.A. Loorbach, R. Lijnis Huffenreuter

To Recognize the Social Value of Mitigation Actions in a Climate Agreement , December 7, 2015, Dominique Finon

Thinking ‘Eco-Systemically’ to Shift the Trillions , December 7, 2015, Romain Morel, Ian Cochran

The price of carbon: ways forward after COP-21 , November 26, 2015, Christian de Perthuis, Pierre-André Jouvet, Raphaël Trotignon

Towards a Sustainable Financial System , November 26, 2015, Armin Haas

Environmental policy performance bonds , November 12, 2015, Abdeldjellil Bouzidi, Michael Mainelli

Is the exchange rate – oil price nexus stable over time? , October 26, 2015, Valérie Mignon, Jean-Pierre Allegret, Cécile Couharde

A €120bn investment programme for the European Union’s three-year Juncker Plan , October 22, 2015, Michel Lepetit

Financing the Green Climate Fund , October 22, 2015, Matthias Kroll

Climate Finance in the Context of Sustainable Development , October 22, 2015, Ottmar Edenhofer, Jan Christoph Steckel, Michael Jakob

How Could We Finance Low-Carbon Investments in Europe? , October 22, 2015, Michel Aglietta, Etienne Espagne, Vincent Aussilloux

Why Finance Can Save the Planet , October 15, 2015, Jean Pisani-Ferry

After TPP: the EU shouldn’t rush into concluding TTIP , October 15, 2015, Sébastien Jean

The “$100 000 000 000 per year” question , October 8, 2015, Christian De Perthuis, Pierre-André Jouvet

Supporting the energy transition: the role of low interest rates , October 1, 2015, Pierre Monnin

The Role of International Financial Institutions, Central Banks and Monetary Policies in the Low-Carbon Transition , October 1, 2015, Colin Hines

Financial Innovation and The State: Lessons for 21st Century Climate Finance from the 19th Century Railways Era , October 1, 2015, Dipak Dasgupta

Positive Pricing of Carbon Reduction: A Low Hanging Fruit , September 22, 2015, Alfredo Sirkis

What Role for Financial Supervisors in Addressing Systemic Environmental Risk? , September 22, 2015, Rens van Tilburg

An Investment Climate for Climate Investment , September 22, 2015, Sam Fankhauser

Sovereign debt restructuring: alternative solutions , September 24, 2015, Christophe Destais

How to Finance the Low Carbon Transition: The Role of the Financial System , September 17, 2015, Etienne Espagne, Baptiste Perrissin Fabert

The exit from the U.S. zero interest-rate policy should be done gradually , September 18, 2015, Stéphane Lhuissier, Fabien Tripier

China: what are the motivations of the recent depreciation of the RMB? , September 14, 2015, Christophe Destais

Four Roadblocks to a Global Climate Agreement , September 18, 2015, Jean Pisani-Ferry

Guideposts for low-carbon finance , September 18, 2015, Billy Pizer

Reorienting financial intermediation towards sustainable financing: Bangladesh Bank’s approach , September 18, 2015, M.A.M. Kazemi

More Political Economy on Global Warming and a Proposition , September 18, 2015, Michel Aglietta, Etienne Espagne

Was the IMF right to come to the rescue of Greece in 2010? , June 30, 2015, Christophe Destais

Structural reforms: why did the term become so "toxic"? , May 29, 2015, Sophie Piton

What could be Japan contribution to COP 21? , May 28, 2015, Evelyne Dourille-Feer

The Chinese game of Go in the international financial system , May 12, 2015, Christophe Destais

Volatility and uncertainty are not the same! , May 4, 2015, Valérie Mignon, Marc Joëts, Tovonony Razafindrabe

Back to the Great Moderation? , April 30, 2015, Stéphane Lhuissier

Regulatory coherence is more easily said than done , April 23, 2015, Sébastien Jean

Europe is trapped by its competitiveness obsession , April 22, 2015, Sébastien Jean

QE - "European style": be bolder, but parsimonious! , March 24, 2015, Urszula Szczerbowicz, Natacha Valla

Quantitative Easing: were markets surprised? , January 24, 2015, Stéphane Lhuissier

ECB equity purchases: too risky, really? , January 9, 2015, Urszula Szczerbowicz, Natacha Valla

Best wishes for 2015 ! , December 23, 2014, CEPII

Long live the Juncker Plan! , December 21, 2014, Natacha Valla

Is China finally inhaling the smoke of international financial markets? , December 16, 2014, Christophe Destais

TTIP is about regulatory coherence , December 8, 2014, Lionel Fontagné, Sébastien Jean

Purchases of sovereign bonds: the ECB confronted with the heterogeneity of the Euro area , December 4, 2014, Urszula Szczerbowicz

The delusion of State guarantees , October 3, 2014, Natacha Valla

Reforming the European Investment Bank: a New Architecture for Public Investment in Europe , July 30, 2014, Natacha Valla

China’s Roadmap to Harmonious Society , June 12, 2014, Michel Aglietta, Guo Bai

The euro area urgently needs a Federal Investment Fund (not a budget) , April 9, 2014, Natacha Valla

Euro area: deflation is the wrong debate , March 6, 2014, Natacha Valla

The French should care about Karlsruhe , February 12, 2014, Natacha Valla

Swapmania , December 9, 2013, Christophe Destais

Negative interest rate on bank deposits at the central bank: an option for the ECB? , November 27, 2013, Urszula Szczerbowicz

WTO: Rethinking the special and differential treatment granted to developing countries , October 8, 2013, Sébastien Jean

Significant economic gains could be achieved through a transatlantic trade partnership , September 23, 2013, Lionel Fontagné, Julien Gourdon, Sébastien Jean

Emerging turbulences , September 10, 2013, Christophe Destais

Is the Eurozone really a monetary union? (2/2) , July 3, 2013, Christophe Destais

Is the Eurozone really a monetary union? (1/2) , July 1, 2013, Christophe Destais

The banking union needs a guarantor of last resort , June 17, 2013, Christophe Destais

Fast rising inequality in China: what can be done about it? , May 15, 2013, Guanghua Wan

Challenges ahead for the next WTO DG , May 2, 2013, Sébastien Jean

Round-tripping of Russian foreign investment via Cyprus , March 18, 2013, Olena Havrylchyk, Svetlana Ledyaeva

IMF Quota Formula Review: still a long way to go , February 20, 2013, Christophe Destais

Monetary policy in exceptional times , January 31, 2013, Urszula Szczerbowicz

Sébastien Jean was appointed director of CEPII , December 18, 2012, CEPII

Ending the euro area crisis: crossing the river by feeling the stones , December 13, 2012, Benjamin Carton, Christophe Destais, Sophie Piton

The interbank market one year after Mario Draghi presidency at the ECB , November 19, 2012, Urszula Szczerbowicz

Six pack: the case for a simplified scoreboard , November 14, 2012, Laurence Nayman, Sophie Piton, Agnès Bénassy-Quéré

Importing intermediate goods to foster French firms’ productivity and exports , October 15, 2012, Maria Bas, Vanessa Strauss-Khan

Institutional reform and democracy in Georgia 9 years after the “Rose revolution” , October 4, 2012, Olena Havrylchyk

Financial development in India and firms’ growth , September 21, 2012, Maria Bas, Antoine Berthou

Single bells: single market, single currency, single supervisor, single resolution mechanism , September 14, 2012, Olena Havrylchyk

Internal devaluation: nothing but sweat and tears? , August 7, 2012, Sophie Piton, Yves-Emmanuel Bara

International migration and the new role of preferential trade agreements , July 17, 2012, Gianluca Orefice

The case for the ECB sovereign bonds purchases , July 10, 2012, Urszula Szczerbowicz

China cannot achieve the internationalization of its currency without making it fully convertible , July 2, 2012, Christophe Destais


December 6, 2024
Séminaire compétitivité CEPII-Banque de France "L’Europe au défi de Trump 2.0"


December 11, 2024
America’s Immigration Experience: Lessons from the Past, Perspectives for the Future


December 12, 2024
The 14th Annual International Conference "Immigration in OECD countries"


January 14, 2025
Où va l’économie chinoise ?


    The contents of this issue were finalised December 28, 2012
 

Publisher: SEBASTIEN JEAN, Director of the CEPII
Chief Editor: DOMINIQUE PIANELLI
©CEPII-2004
Address: CEPII - 113, rue Grenelle - 75007 Paris - France
Tel. (33) 1 53 68 55 00 - Fax: (33) 1 53 68 55 03
https://www.cepii.fr